For Better or Worse, the Euro is Here to Stay:
A Response to Eichengreen’s “Is Europe on a
Cross of Gold?”
Since the introduction of the euro as a common
currency on January 1st 1999, it was apparent that the European
monetary union is at the heart of the whole European Union project. The common
currency is the foundation on which the European Union is built, not least
because it improves the allocative efficiency of the price mechanism by
reducing price uncertainty. After all, the reason to have a monetary union in
the first place is to have a strong source of stability in Europe, not just
economically but also politically, by establishing a fully integrated single
goods, services, and financial market. However, since the advent of the Great
Recession, the monetary union has produced disasters, particularly in the
Iberian peninsula and southern Europe: Portugal, Ireland, Italy, Greece, and Spain
(the so called PIIGS) have gone the way of the 1930s with cycles of deflation,
massive banking crises, more sovereign debt, and social and political crises.
Because European governments lack a national currency to depreciate, and lack
the power to relax credit, they face an unbreakable constraint on reflationary
action to counter the massive deflationary shock of the Great Recession. One
popular argument in response to this constraint is to abandon the euro: just as
the gold standard was abandoned after the Great Depression, so too should the euro
be abandoned so that countries have the ability to depreciate their currencies,
and loosen credit. This argument has both pros and cons, but, ultimately, will
not hold: for better or worse, the euro is here to stay.
Four Key
Differences Between the Arguments Against the Gold Standard and the Euro
In his article, “Is Europe on a Cross of Gold”,
Eichengreen states four key differences between the arguments against the gold
standard and the arguments against the euro that leads him to believe “that
maybe—just maybe—the euro will survive” (Eichengreen, 2012). First, the European Central Bank (ECB) has
the capacity to quickly mount a monetary response. By contrast, when there were
many central banks, it was difficult to get them all to move together because
they
viewed
economic prospects through different lenses. Though Eichengreen’s first
difference that the ECB can adopt decisive matters quickly is supported by
empirical evidence, it is not clear to what extent the ECB’s measures, such as
its role in austerity, needs to be adjusted. If the euro were to survive over
the long run, the ECB must be able to quickly identify the outcomes of its
measures, and adjust them as quickly as they implement them. Eichengreen’s second
difference is that the unemployed receive more extensive public support than in
the 1930s (not withstanding recent cuts in social programs), making pressure to
abandon the euro less severe (Eichengreen, 2012). The question that remains to
be answered, however, is “how much
less severe and whether the political center can hold” (Eichengreen, 2012).
Eichengreen’s third key difference is that
political preconditions for a cooperative response are better today: though
political tensions still do exist, particularly between France and Germany, it
is almost certain that they will not begin to rise to the level they were at
during the early 1930s. One important corollary to this argument is that
European countries today are more interconnected—culturally and
economically—and are prepared to work together to save the euro, “fearing that
its collapse would jeopardize their single market” (Eichengreen, 2012). Finally, Eichengreen’s fourth key difference
highlights that abandoning the euro would be substantially more disruptive than
abandoning the gold standard was: “reintroducing the national currency in order
to depreciate it, but leaving the euro value of other financial instruments
untouched, would destroy balance sheets and wreak financial havoc”
(Eichengreen, 2012). In the 1930s, by contrast, bank deposits, along with most
other public and private debt, were denominated in that national currency; when
a European country abandoned the gold standard, all it had to do was, literally
overnight, stop backing their national currency with gold. In short, though
Eichengreen argues that the greater scope of cooperation that exists today
bodes well for the euro, he is quick to highlight that it is the precise
policies on which European governments cooperate that will tell the tale
(Eichengreen, 2012).
Word Count: 718
No comments:
Post a Comment